When the UK government announced its austerity programme in 2010, it believed that private investment would help fill the gap in demand created by cutting public spending, and in particular offset its very large cutsin public investment. That did not happen, and according to OECD forecasts, is not going to happen in a significant way anytime soon.
![]() |
UK Investment Growth (Source, OECD Economic Outlook June 2012) |
The obvious response is for the government to borrow to increase public investment, particularly when it is so cheapto do so. But that is a no-no as far as the Chancellor is concerned. So around the time of the budget it announced its solution to this dilemma. It would provide government guarantees to private investment projects, but it would also encourage the private sector to fund traditional public sector investment, like roads.
Jonathan Portes is rightthat this is a victory of sorts. In particular, it suggests the government believes monetary policy will neither be sufficient to bring about a recovery on its own, nor will monetary policy counteract any attempts through fiscal policy to increase demand. In addition, as lack of demand is the critical problem right now, anything that might help should be welcomed.
However, it has to be said that private finance for public investment appears illogical, as Alasdair Smith argues at the FT today. (See also Martin Wolf earlier.) The only clear ‘advantage’ of this approach is that there will be no immediate impact on the measured public sector deficit. But this policy will increase deficits in the longer term. The bottom line is that taxes will have to rise to pay for this investment, and merely shifting when the deficit increases from the present to the future does not alter this reality.
Unfortunately we have been here before, with the Private Finance Initiative (PFI) used extensively by the previous Labour government. The consequences of PFI are set out in the Office for Budget Responsibility’s (OBR) annual look at the long term position of the UK public finances publishedtoday. It does this in two ways. The first, and most straightforward, is to project those finances over 50 years, a time period over which accounting tricks largely wash out. The second is to calculate ‘Whole Government Accounts’, which attempt to add a measure of future government liabilities to the published debt numbers. The OBR notes that “If all investment undertaken through PFI had been undertaken through conventional debt finance, PSND [public sector net debt] would be around 2.1 per cent of GDP higher than currently measured.”
But it is worse than an attempt to fool the public (and presumably the markets) through bad accounting. The policy is also almost certain to end up costing more. Alasdair Smith suggests that this could involve borrowing at nominal interest rates of 5-7%, compared to interest rates on government debt of around 3%. To quote: “Looking at it another way, the stream of interest and capital repayments that would enable £20m to be raised from private finance would fund between £27m and £34m of public borrowing”.
Professor Smith ends his article with “The OBR should use the platform of its fiscal sustainability report to give strong advice on how best to finance infrastructure investment.” Unfortunately for the time being at least he will be disappointed. As I have notedbefore, when the OBR was set up the government was very careful to ensure that its mandate involved crunching numbers but not looking at alternative policies, let alone giving policy advice. From the point of view of good public policy, that was a serious mistake, precisely because it makes it easier for the government to get away with accounting tricks that end up costing the public a lot of money.
0 Comments